1

Where are the new private sector central banks?

For the past 8 years banks have had it rough. Partly they had themselves to blame, partly this is the result of lax (or light touch, or ‘growth oriented’ stimulative) government legislation and action. Anti-banking public opinion and the subsequent more stringent state aid rules and bail in requirements are currently preventing public sector measures that are needed to create short-term financial stability. Now in the news are Monte dei Paschi di Siena and Deutsche Bank, but similar stories have been available in the past across the EU, and at certain times in e.g. the USA and China. For troubled banks there do not appear to be voluntary private sector interventions, and forcefully ‘inviting’ stronger banks to buy their weaker brethren does not work because either the stronger banks are too strong relative to their supervisor, or too weak to bear the cross alone, or are themselves part of the weaker side of the system. Normally the state balance sheet would now be used to prop up the relevant bits of the financial infrastructure. Examples of such traditional public sector solutions for banks overwhelmed by non performing loans, sovereign/bank cross infection (now more often in the modus that new or old bad fiscal decisions and doubts about sovereign debts are infecting their banks in e.g. the UK, Italy and in Greece) would be e.g. nationalisation or a state aid loan at non-market rates or conditions. Even though such measures are often financially beneficial to the investing state in the long term, the potential for high-risk and especially the sheer amount of money needed for the initial public investment has influenced the introduction of barriers to public sector intervention. More specifically, any use of public funds now needs to be preceded by the bail-in of shareholders, junior bondholders and then senior creditors, such as current account holders above 100.000 euro. Creatively, Italy has introduced its Atlante/Atlas fund as a private sector alternative to state aid, but there are continuing doubts whether the Italian financial sector, based in an over-indebted country, is sturdy enough as a whole for the least weak institutions to help out their weakest colleagues.
Even though at least three of the legs of a banking union (EBA in the whole of the EU, and SRM and SSM in the Eurozone) are now in their operational phase, the responsibility for coming up with the funding for solutions appears to continue to be territorial. The SRM is still building up its funding, and it is no doubt difficult to determine when it should grasp the reins from the SSM and take control and responsibility for a concrete solution. In the mean time, local funds and savings account holders tend to be the biggest category of bail-inable creditors, once the more sophisticated financial sector investors have decided not to invest in shares or coco’s of a troubled bank, or are dumping such shares or bail-inable bonds at the first hint of trouble. In the case of amongst others Italy, this is a political issue as a recent bail-in showed that many of the bail-inable creditors are consumers and small and medium sized enterprises. Agreeing that the Single Resolution Board of the SRM takes charge, means accepting that these voters will suffer. These are the same taxpayers who were supposed to benefit from the fact that ‘taxpayer money’ should only be in play after bail-in had taken place (but instead suffer most). The least sophisticated players are the most likely investors in the bail-inable unsecured bank bonds that at the moment do not pay a credible risk premium in the central bank stimulated low interest environment. A territorial approach does not work in a rich but stretched country such as Italy, however, nor is the health of Italian banks of interest only to other Italian banks, the health of Deutsche or the smaller community banks only of interest to Germany, or the health of the UK financial system upon Brexit only of interest to other UK banks. The reputation and financial health of all banks in the Eurozone, in the EU, and perhaps even in the world are now soundly linked in our open financial system, with information, distrust and fear propagating quickly on the internet. This should make it in the joint interest of the member states and governments of other financial centres to stand together, but the aforementioned public opinion and a sovereign tradition of not helping each other across borders when there are solvency issues at banking groups of which the top holding is licensed elsewhere, are preventing this.
Nothing is, however, preventing banks and other key bits of the international financial infrastructure such as CCP’s to step up themselves. Regardless of whether Atlante/Atlas was voluntary or set up under political pressure, it would appear in the calculated self-interest of such institutions to create – as they did some decades or in some cases such as the UK centuries ago – a new central bank from their midst, to deal with this issue that no bank or member state can deal with unilaterally. Strong appearing financial groups can become weak almost overnight if the banking system is distrusted or an incident in one of their subsidiaries occurs (AIG, Citi, Deutsche, Unicredit, RBS, Fortis are examples that come to mind), so it would be in wise for both currently high ranking and for currently low ranking banks to participate in a new private sector bail-out structure that would be able, allowed and willing to act. And no doubt such a EU or worldwide private sector bail-out fund could count on a high rating, and a low tax environment, especially if it is set up as a charity instead of as a profit centre (perhaps with any profits allocated to help out bail-in victims, or to sponsor financial education of consumers and small enterprises). Taking action themselves, jointly, in the common interest but by voluntarily putting up their own money would not least also give a valid emotional argument for allowing them to set their own course again, instead of being regulated to the max as is the current regulatory trajectory for the still nominally ‘private’ sector activity of banking, and thus take control of their own destiny again by also picking up the tab if things go wrong.
This is because depression will not tadalafil india online unica-web.com only affect you mentally but also physically as well. tadalafil in canada Make sure that a stimulant of romantic and sexual nature exists. These days’ problems like sexual dysfunction, premature ejaculation, erectile dysfunction, penis shrinkage and low sex unica-web.com sildenafil tablets uk desire. Benefits levitra vs cialis of these coupons are you get the medication that differs from generic drug only by its known name. So my question would be to the banks: where is the new private sector central bank?




Bail-in or bail-instability

Banking supervisors and legislators have opted firmly for the bail-in tool as a key part of crisis management at banks. According to the FSB, the EU competition authorities and the EU banking regulators, bail-in is the critical element in any scenario to resolve a bank that is in financial trouble. Before state aid can be dispensed, capital and the (newly reinvented tier 3 capital under another name) bail-inable debt capital requirement under the banking resolution and recovery directive needs to be written down in part or in full, or converted into shares. State aid includes any form of investment (equity or loans) at non-market terms, and includes the dispensation of money from the recently introduced resolution funds (because these funds are government controlled, even though they are funded by the banking sector). There have now been some minor try-outs of crisis management built around a bail-in at failing bank, for instance in Cyprus and Italy. In the absence of sufficient share capital, these try-outs have also involved bailing in depositors who had more than 100.000 euro (the deposit guarantee limit in the EU) entrusted to the failing bank, as well as bailing in consumers who unwittingly bought ‘saving certificates’ that turned out to be subordinated bonds (the term ‘subordinated’ means the same as the term ‘blah blah’ to many depositors).

If the state does not bear the risk, who does?

In Cyprus, the announcement of a bail-in of protected depositors caused social instability to the extent that bail-in enforcers backed down. In the final scenario, only the amount of deposits over 100.000 euro were bailed in. In Italy, the social repercussions of bailing in poor consumers who bought a subordinated piece of paper may well also lead to backtracking on the bail-in. A possible route would be by (ex post) declaring that selling subordinated bonds to consumers constitutes misselling, for which damages will need to be paid to the consumer (to the extent of the bailed-in amount, de facto annulling the bail-in). Though selling bonds or shares or subordinated deposits to only slightly financially aware retail investors did not seem to disturb anyone prior to the crisis, selling coco’s and similar paper already appears to be on the radar of conduct of business supervisors as most likely unsuitable for consumers. A high-risk investment in any bail-inable debt (under bail-in rules including senior unsecured debt, or savings exceeding 100.000 euro) may indeed well be prohibited as unsuitable for non-financially educated consumers and small companies (which can only be supported). These partial retrenchments of the scope of bail-in so far only concerned consumers, however, though both consumers and the financial system as a whole may also be harmed by bailing in claims on a failing bank held by of other banks, pension funds, insurers and so on. The likelihood of such damage to the financial system and directly or indirectly or to large groups of retail clients of bailed in financial institutions increases if a bail-in would ever need to be performed at a systemic bank.

Lacking impact assessment of the bail-in tool

Research on the consequences of a bail-in is still in its infancy. A detailed impact assessment appears to be lacking, with the main driver of bail-in legislation being that ‘the taxpayer’, whomever that may be, needs to be prevented from having to foot the bill of state intervention at systemic banks and other systemic financial institutions. Most likely, ‘the taxpayer’ is one of the consumers or companies (or public authorities), whose claim on the bank is being bailed in, or the beneficiary of pensions or insurance pay outs by pension funds and insurers whose claims on a failing bank are being bailed in. Whether concentrating this pain on the few entities with a direct link to the bank is fair or not is debatable, but it certainly will mean that these unhappy few will be less profitable companies, poorer consumers, and loss making financial investors, who will pay less taxes, buy less stuff and employ fewer people in the future. Tax income will thus likely be reduced, possibly to the same extent (or higher) than a more traditional form of state aid would amount to. This will almost certainly be the case after deducting future income from selling the ‘investment’ (now funded by state aid) in a failing bank, or by recouping emergency loans made to a formerly failing bank. The main effect of a bail-in requirement may well be that the pay out for crisis resolution is now channelled directly between investors end creditors/depositors and the bank, instead of via the sovereign balance sheet, though the net effect on both the balance sheet of the state and of retail clients and financial institution may be the same or worse.

What I personally would like to know, as guesswork is all we have now, is what would actually happen to the financial system and to the taxpayers if the bail-in tool would be applied to one of the bigger banks. I think this is also essential information for any banking supervisor or crisis manager such as the Eurozone Single Resolution Fund before they apply the bail-in tool to any systemic bank, to avoid creating financial instability. So far the tool has mainly been applied to minnows amongst the banks, and even there it has hurt. Can we ask EBA, the ESRB, the SRB, the ECB, the BIS and/or the FSB, to perform a stress scenario including a bail-in to each banking group that is deemed ‘systemic’?

The proper application of this wonder solution under the proper care of a registered dietician, and that is what people who made the lie up were unable to understand. buying viagra from canada Men taking nitrates or alpha-blockers (antihypertensive drug) are not allowed to relax and receive blood. prescription de levitra If anything Jelly pills are anything but rubbery. viagra prescription Other men are usually seen cialis generico online http://appalachianmagazine.com/2018/0/page/10/ preferring treatment without their partner’s knowledge. Possible stress scenario test, first round effects

In such a stress scenario, a bail-in would be applied for instance after a year of severe losses that either were written down from equity or added to formal or informal sets of non-performing loans (the latter by banks that had no spare equity to write down, and by supervisors that wanted to avoid having to face the possibility of formally declaring a bank bankrupt on their watch). After such a prolonged deterioration of a banks’ health a full bail in is performed. In that case, how much would be bailed in of (1) public authorities investment (i.e. public shareholdings in banks such as SNS or RBS, as well as deposits by states and local authorities), (2) how much would be bailed in of loans or investment held by other banks (in the traditional domino-style financial instability scenario), (3) how much of loans and investments held by a pension fund/life insurer/investment fund, (4) how much of loan and investments by regular companies, and (5) how much of loans and investments by consumers. If this kind of information is not known in advance, then bailing in a systemic bank is just opening a black box of misery, similar to the repercussions of the unknown spread of risk in the financial system through securitisation bonds composed of bad quality US subprime mortgages, which were the starting point of the most recent financial crisis. The outcome of this first set of questions would only be first round effects (compounded if multiple banks would be subjected to the bail-in tool at the same time).

Second round effects

Once the information on the first set of questions on the above stress test is available, it would be interesting to assess whether those write downs would be concentrated in the uneducated part of the consumer pool, and at financially naive enterprises (and there is no reason to assume that industrial enterprises, restaurants, plumbers and bakers are financially educated enough to know that any surplus on their accounts over 100.000 euro would be bailed in, nor that most pension funds have the staff and expertise to monitor their banks). Equally, it would be interesting to investigate how many of the more educated and rich would have scampered away well before the bail-in once rumours of potential losses at a large bank would start to circulate. Lastly, it would be relevant to know the second round effects on tax income and economic growth, as well as on the pay-out (and thus taxable income) by pension funds and life insurers to retirees? And how would that over time (e.g. five years) compare to the more traditional scenario of a state funded bail-out, of which I would guess between 60 and 120 % is recouped after divestment of the bailed out systemic bank, or in the case of smaller banks: a liquidation scenario of a solvent but illiquid bank?

Final remarks

Introducing the bail-in tool in the crisis management of banks may well prove to be opportune. So far, however, there is mainly evidence to the contrary, with a loss of trust in banks and in banking regulators when consumers are bailed in. When systemic banks are bailed in, this may well turn out to lead to disproportional losses for the least financially educated. If in the future the claims of more educated parties are bailed in at failing systemic banks, this may lead to domino effects that lead to financial instability, and/or to bigger losses for ‘the taxpayer’ than under the more traditional state aid scenario. Until this is investigated, a bail-in at a larger bank may well trigger our next financial system crisis if that risk turns out to lie in unknown and vulnerable places. Further research is thus urgently needed.




Designing an alternative prudential regime for simple banks

There has been a race between banks and regulators to add size and complexity to banking groups on the one hand and to regulations that cover such businesses on the other. It is questionable that smaller and simpler banks and their clients are best served by this development. At the same time, the financial system suffers due to a lack of diversely set up banks, with varied types of loans and interest rates on offer and with business models that are not prone to fail at exactly the same time.

If only it were possible to say in advance which banks will be dangerous in the future. In that case the solution would be simply to abolish most rules for the non-dangerous type. Crystal balls are in short supply, however, and time after time, both big and small banks have surprised regulators by being unpredictably safe, or unsafe, and if unsafe, by suddenly being systemically important (or politically important) at their point of failure. Legislators and supervisors do not like such surprises, and have responded by adding ever more detail to the Basel (and EU) capital framework and the Basel core principles for banking supervision. The original framework was drafted at a time when the ‘big, diversified and internationally active banks’ for which it was written were of the size that small banks are now, and capital markets and markets in financial instruments were relatively simple. Open borders in the EU single market (and around the world for some financial services) have since allowed a consolidation wave between banks operating in ever larger, more complex and interlinked financial markets, for which the original rules no longer appeared to suffice. This consolidation is then reinforced by the need for size to absorb the costs of stricter rules, and in times of crisis by supervisors begging relatively stable banks to take over relatively wobbly banks.

So now we appear to be stuck in a set of complex rules designed for complex banks and complex financial systems. And strangely, in many submarkets such bigger banks are behaving in exactly the same manner, dropping small borrowers as reviewing and monitoring them is too complex, dropping trade finance and USA linked clients because there are too high AML or FATCA administrative burdens associated with them, targeting exactly the same profitable and asset rich clients to offer loans to, and offering depositors the same tawdry deals because for large banks the wholesale funding market is both simpler, more predictable and cheaper than managing a plenitude of surly savers. Especially if having such depositors means higher fees to be paid to deposit guarantee funds, resolution funds, supervisors fees, and likely to local tax authorities.

The traditional EU approach to the capital framework has been that all banks should be on the same level playing field, and that the so-called proportionality principle will provide for enough flexibility to allow smaller and simpler banks to thrive. But how to apply the rules proportionally, when it is not clear for smaller banks that their supervisors will accept anything less than perfection, and for supervisors that leeway granted to their banks will not come back to haunt them when that bank fails? There is no safe haven for either banks and supervisors to hide from liability or bad publicity if something goes wrong that could have been prevented if rules to calculate requirements or set up a check and balances system could have been enforced too.

Now, it could be defended that the complex rules serve a useful purpose for complex banks. Their business is driven by a need to reduce regulatory capital requirements, and to prevent innovative abuse or avoidance the regulators have to be equally innovative to think up new detailed rules or guidance. In the absence of minimum capital requirements their sheer size otherwise might mean that in the eyes of the financial markets they can get away with even more minimal safety measures as long as they appear to be profitable. This is not the case for relatively smaller banks, where the amount of capital needed to be able to attract wholesale funding is often higher than the amount of regulatory capital required under solvency ratio calculations. For these smaller banks, the absolute number of regulatory capital requirements is not so much the burden, but the sheer size of administrative and reporting measures that are needed to be able to calculate this via the solvency ratio. And this burden is difficult to make proportional to their business, as the main elements that support that calculation need to be present in the same manner in both big and small banks to be able to come to a trustworthy outcome of standardised or internal models on which the solvency ratio is based.

Creating a lot of lightly regulated shadow-competitors for banks (such as via e-money, payment institutions, venture capital or social investment fund rules) does not solve the fact that the traditional basis of banking, attracting deposits, making loans, providing facilities, and thus easing the functioning of the economy, is becoming the prerogative of ever larger organisations that can optimize the regulatory burden of solvency ratio calculations.

If regulators and the remaining smaller and simpler banks are truly interested in more competition between banks, more choice for clients (both lenders and borrowers), more diversity in the banking sector, more effective rules, or at least less complex rules, then substantial changes in the prudential regime should be considered. Though it is easy to be married to the status quo of the Basel capital accord, it should be remembered that it is a relatively young framework of barely 40 or 50 years of age, that has been growing organically, and was never intended for the simplest banks, but for the most systemic banks of its day and age. And there are alternatives that still are based on available experience in the way banking was structured in the past, or how it is structured for state licensed banks in the USA, or how supervision is structured in the insurance sector.

In order to be contemplated by regulators, however, any alternative regime will need to be more effective than the current regime in preventing harmful fallout of a banks’ failure. Though the existing set of complex rules has a dismal track record during various crisis, there is a belief (though that belief possibly only exists in press releases) that the various untested add-ons of the last few years will work better in limiting the potential for future crisis. This even though for instance the much admired bail-in instrument has the potential to cause contagion in the bailed-in creditors, and harsher market risk requirements risk reducing the liquidity of markets in certain financial instruments. While waiting for the jury report on the effectiveness of the new add-ons to arrive during the next crisis, that belief in their sturdiness is a political reality. If an alternative simpler regime is even to be contemplated, the alternative simpler banks subject to it should thus be even more ‘safe’. Preferably, any legislator and supervisor that replaces part of the current regime for a simpler alternative should be able to honestly say that they do not care to have e.g. full control and complex data over the bank, because the public interest is fully managed in another way. In my opinion, this other way could be found by making the failure of such simple alternative banks irrelevant for the protection of their clients, and irrelevant to the financial system in which they operate. This will only work if the banks’ full failure hurts no one except the bank itself and its equity providers, not even if similar or related banks would fail at the same time. So if we would like more diversity in the banking sector, and allow some banks to compete on different conditions without undermining safety nor a level playing field, a new balance would need to be struck by deleting the most onerous obligations of the current regime for simple alternative banks, and replacing them with equally safety enhancing but more simple alternative measures.

Smaller and simpler banks appear to suffer most from the calculation, supporting organisational requirements, and pillar 3 and regulatory reporting requirements that relate to the solvency ratio. For non-complex banks, as indicated above, these requirements actually do not even result in a credible minimum capital level in the opinion of the banks themselves and/or the markets (small banks operate at higher capital levels than the minimum required). These solvency ratio calculations thus appear to be surplus to annual accounting calculations. While these regulatory requirements do not bind them, they still induce costs and force banks into specific business models. But ditching the solvency ratio requirements and all adherent organisation and reporting burdens, would be a large shift from the current regime, and would force supervisors out of their comfort zone. Even when the results of imposing the solvency ratio are thus far underwhelming and their limitations badly understood; their usefulness as one of the few means of control and – even if ex post – verification is at the moment not paralleled by other measures.

Nevertheless, I would propose deleting the solvency ratio calculation and all supporting requirements in full for a subset of simple alternative banks, subject to a range of conditions. Any tinkering with the solvency ratio – which evidently is in the comfort zone of regulators and supervisors – would not result in a measurable reduction in burdens, while only adding to the small forest of trees cut down to be able to print the so-called single rulebook now. The conditions for escaping the solvency ratio obligations should be simple and at the same time compensate for its loss, and prevent abuse. They should thus include the majority of the following:

  • Personal liability of all current and (recent) past members of management and anyone ‘owning’ or ‘controlling’ the bank e.g. by having a stake of more than 10% of equity. Introducing collective responsibility in this manner would make banks again more similar to the out of fashion partnership-based banks, and force key influencers to face up to potential negative consequences of their or their partners’ decisions. An alternative could be a non-profit bank with mandatory low salaries and a prohibition on dividends and bonuses, but this would require some talented people to be willing to work for a fraction of their commercial salary solely for idealistic reasons.
  • A leverage ratio based solely on comparing existing annual account information set at a high number (e.g. 10% or more, to be calibrated at the high capital levels smaller banks now have), combined with an FDIC style prompt corrective action tool. This could be supplemented by other indicators of health, but only if those are based on already available public annual accounts data.
  • Limiting the asset side of the bank, by reintroducing the habit to issue limited banking licenses. For instance licensing such banks to be focused on SME finance, or on trade finance, or on infrastructure investing, or on mortgage loans. This is still an existing feature in the insurance sector, where the main type of insurance written by any specific licensed entity has to quite similar, e.g. limited to car insurance, or to fire insurance. Apart from their specialisation on the asset side, their business should only consist of deposit taking and offering payment accounts. This would clarify their transformation function, and ensure that their management can be focused on a specific business.
  • General demands on management, valuation and bookkeeping sufficient for annual accounts and conduct of business purposes could remain in place.
  • No deposits or credits should be accepted that are not fully guaranteed by a public deposit guarantee fund; or that are fully collateralized/insured by repo’s, covered bonds, credit default swaps or by other credit insurance. It could be contemplated to prescribe that a proportion of the deposits should be term deposits, though any simple alternative bank with a personally liable management is certain to keep a good liquidity buffer if they have immediately redeemable deposits.
  • The maximum market share of such simple alternative banks in each specified banking activity they can be active in under their licenses, should be set at a level that ensures that both the deposit guarantee fund and the financial system could relatively easily absorb the net losses that will be suffered due to their potential for – even collective – failure (in a more strict version of the USA concentration limits).
  • Such a bank should have all its activities within the same legal entity. It should be prohibited from having subsidiaries, should not be allowed to make loans to group entities, and should only be allowed to outsource to non-related entities that would not fail in case of its failure. If it is part of a group (e.g. a automotive group, or even a financial group), such a license can only be issued to one simple alternative bank per group. It should be supervised solely on a solo and stand-alone basis, and the parent group should be ignored except as an ex-post suable party in case of the demise of the bank. The equity share in a alternative simple bank by any ‘normal’ parent bank should be weighed solely as a capital investment both for solo and consolidated supervision purposes on its parent bank (to avoid solvency ratio requirements landing indirectly at the alternative simple bank).
  • Instead of a supplementary pillar 2 regime, it should have a stand-alone annual obligation to write a business plan with its main business options and risks, and what it plans to do on both accounts.
  • Its resolution plan should be simple: full liquidation, repaying the deposit guarantee fund for protecting its depositors, combined with the liquidator maximising the size of the estate by suing the liable persons within its structure for any deficit in repaying the DGS and other (collateralized) creditors.
  • They should be identified by a separate name that highlights frailty (bank light, mini bank, high risk bank, or even alternative simple bank).

This is a much more convenient way of buying these medicines, on top of that, it offers them a chance to rise above their online viagra mastercard physical anomalies and lead a healthy sexual life! A sexual issue ought to be done as right on time as would be prudent. The tadalafil 5mg tablets sound waves travel into the muscle to record the electrical activity in that muscle. The inability to perform well during the process of sexual intercourse. buy cialis on line When you’ve got large help away from your family and as well as off the entire those individuals who can see you may help you the treatment of personal anxiety. cialis generico mastercard
If the bank or its equity providers want to abandon these restrictions, they can of course opt into the solvency ratio regime, perhaps with even the liability for new obligations incurred after the transfer slowly tapering off (though some form of collective liability of all key influencers would be good at any bank). For new start ups, this would have the benefit that by the time they would like to do so, they have had the chance to build up both their organisation and their expertise up to the required level to be able to work in that more complex environment. During a try-out phase for this new regime, it could be envisaged that such alternative simple banks should not operate on a cross border basis. Anything longer than during a try-out period would, however, irreparably damage the concept of the EU single market.

Whether such a regime-change is credible remains to be seen. It is out of the comfort zone of EU and Basel regulators (no more solvency ratio?) and latter day bankers (liability?). If banks and regulators are indeed serious in their concerns about the current regime and its impact on the way the banking sector performs its functions to the benefit of all of us, it should nonetheless be considered.

 

Also see:

Are EU Banks Safe?

Actal advice to the Dutch Minister of finance, Regulatory burdens on credit, 23 July 2015, plus the accompanying EY report of May 2015 (both in Dutch)

CEBS, results of the comprehensive quantitative impact study, 16 December 2010, www.eba.europa.eu. Also see BCBS, An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impact of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements, August 2010, www.bis.org.




Lessons from Volkswagen testing software for IRB banks

The VW manipulation of its emissions testing results provides lessons for banks, insurers and their supervisors. Testlab results bear no similarity to real life survival or failure is a simple one. Bad governance structures can lead to bad decisions (as highlighted by John Plender in the FT and supported by a wide range of examples such as the DSB Bank failure in the Netherlands). Another lesson is that the testlab/models that are the basis for calculating capital requirements are prone to pressure and manipulation.

There appear to have been two stages that shifted the results in response to high-level orders to pass environmental tests and improve sales. The first is the – as I understand – industry standard in the EU that emissions are only tested in laboratory conditions on vehicles that are specially selected and prepared for this testing by stripping off all inconvenient aspects (rear view mirrors, wipers, and anything that weighs anything in the car that is not needed to make it run, such as the standard airconditioning or audio equipment). For some this is the minor league of evasion or fraud as it ‘only’ changes the hardware, and anyone actually looking would notice. Even for this type of lab-adaptation there is little relation between the car in the lab and on the road, but some people would say it remains in the nudge and wink category of how smart it is to evade the vague requirements and the light touch oversight, and the general contours of the car tested remain the same. The second stage is now provoking more outrage, as the manipulation is not in the visible hardware, but in lines of code in the software. Any instrument that supposedly cleans up the emissions but was a drag on ease of handling on the road was automatically switched off by the design of the software, except when the exact conditions of the laboratory test were found.

Though it is unlikely that executives removed the hardware from the testlab-models or wrote the software that changed the car from fake circumstances to real life riding and back, it is likely that they created the incentives to do so by demanding relative growth as compared to competitors, in the cars case by simultaneously demanding low emissions during tests so that the cars could legally be sold, and high performance so that customers would actually want to buy them, and did not bother to sufficiently check whether the product sold fit the description on issues that customers did not bother to verify or sue on, and regulators did not bother to/were not able to check.

The calculation of capital requirements is open to similar pressures. It is abstract, only important if thousands of products fail to perform at the same time, only important in the long term, and customers do not like it while the bank or insurer is alive because it heightens their costs if the bank or insurer would take it seriously. The old standardised approach for capital requirements calculation was abandoned for complex institutions because the choices made in investments were optimized by these institutions to take the highest risk/reward road within each wide basket of types of assets, such as corporate bonds. This maximized returns while minimizing costly capital requirements. The newly invented ‘internal’ models that have been introduced for banks in the 2004 Basel II accord (in the EU implemented via the 2006 version of the CRD) and will be introduced for insurers in 2016 under Solvency II allow more leeway to reward the bank or insurer if they choose a less risky product to invest in, but does expect them to take better regard of the more risky products too. Some banks are indeed relatively conservative or are being forced to be relative conservative by their supervisors, and estimate the riskiness of the assets they hold higher than the models used by their competitors estimate the same or the same type of assets. Some banks, however, are removing the airconditioning and audio systems by abandoning newly capital-costly areas such as trade finance or investment banking, while plunging collectively into low capital-costly areas, or professing high confidence in their clients or risk management systems. The result is that banks’ internal models show wildly different results, which is an indicator that some may be too lightly capitalised for the risks they run in their entire business. An additional result is that worthy areas of services are no longer provided by banks, but are either not provided, or are now provided by less regulated service providers. It is likely that more conservatively calculating banks are under pressure to become more ‘capital efficient’ in order to retain profitability and competitiveness.

The temptation to adapt the outcomes of test-results is easy to understand. Lower capital requirements (emissions) lead to the potential for acquiring more assets (making more sales) that generate higher profits and higher status for the CEO. And a slight tweak in one area that makes the boss happy does not really impact a lot on the overall capital; except of course if this happens in all areas the bank or insurer is active in. These tweaks stimulate the financial company, their shareholders and the economy as long as the bank or insurer makes no losses yet. And the internal models used by complex banks do not show with a big blinking warning whether there is internal pressure to always lean in the same direction. Fundamental attitudes towards the need for buffers or the need for speed and profits are neither measured nor checked easily, especially if the number of experts is vastly larger on the bank’s side than on the supervisors’ side. But if the general attitude at a financial company is that it is acceptable to have slight manipulations, or just slightly reducing the riskiness of the asset just by removing the dragging mirrors from the test-lab model, this risks the continued survival of the firm once it comes out. Removing trade finance already does not make the bank safer. It just makes it less well capitalised, and diminishes the value of the bank to society similar to cars with high Nox emissions in real life. Especially harmful would be if it turns out that the models used by banks are deliberately built to optimise testlab results that bear no relation to known market and firm behaviour when risks materialise. Bankers/Insurers would, however, not be unique in such manipulation. The regulated bits of internal models and the standardised models are riddled with such deliberate misdesign by lawmakers, e.g. to underestimate the riskiness of SME-loans, or to hugely underestimate the riskiness of sovereign bonds. In the end, if banks add to this, and do not compensate for design-faults in the laws that rule the design of models to calculate capital by adding voluntary layers of safety themselves, it remains deceit towards clients, investors, and society as a whole.

Though supervisors are aware of the discrepancies, they have been kicking the can down the road for a while, and there are no signs yet of an official line. The amount of capital needed for the most derelict banks – and the financial stability consequences of exposing them – may pressure them into regulatory forbearance. Though this is both understandable and damnable at the same time, such regulatory forbearance does not impact on the own responsibility of bank and insurance boards on whose watch such collective leaning or manipulation takes place by underlings who aim to please their bosses by improved headline numbers.

Safety should not be tampered with, and will not be tampered with in the long run, as the sheltered executives of VW already found out.

 

Also see:

  • Plender, John, Poor governance at VW should have been a warning to investors, FT 30 September 2015
  • Noonan, Laura, ECB doubles the time needed to review banks’ risk models, FT 16 August 2015
  • EBA reports of 22 July 2015 on eba.europa.eu
  • BCBS, Regulatory Consistency Assessment Programme (RCAP) Analysis of Risk-Weighted Assets for Market Risk, January 2013 (rev February 2013)
  • BCBS, Regulatory Consistency Assessment Programme (RCAP) Analysis of Risk-Weighted Assets for Credit Risk in the Banking Book, July 2013
  • UK FSA, A Regulatory Response to the Global Banking Crisis; Discussion Paper 09/2, March 2009, page 71-73

The color of Kamagra pill is different that that of the cheapest viagra in uk because it is the rule of nature and change always comes for good. With the help of spinal commander cialis decompression by a professional healthcare provider at initial phase of treatment. Kilham decided to get a look at the laborious task of unseating the vertical root of the famed Eurycoma Longifolia cialis prices appalachianmagazine.com tree for himself. If you not treated this problem properly, they could advance lead to erectile dysfunction or impotence is concerned. cialis super active
 

  • EU Banking Supervision, chapter 6.3
  • Are EU Banks Safe?, chapter 4.5