1

Where are the new private sector central banks?

For the past 8 years banks have had it rough. Partly they had themselves to blame, partly this is the result of lax (or light touch, or ‘growth oriented’ stimulative) government legislation and action. Anti-banking public opinion and the subsequent more stringent state aid rules and bail in requirements are currently preventing public sector measures that are needed to create short-term financial stability. Now in the news are Monte dei Paschi di Siena and Deutsche Bank, but similar stories have been available in the past across the EU, and at certain times in e.g. the USA and China. For troubled banks there do not appear to be voluntary private sector interventions, and forcefully ‘inviting’ stronger banks to buy their weaker brethren does not work because either the stronger banks are too strong relative to their supervisor, or too weak to bear the cross alone, or are themselves part of the weaker side of the system. Normally the state balance sheet would now be used to prop up the relevant bits of the financial infrastructure. Examples of such traditional public sector solutions for banks overwhelmed by non performing loans, sovereign/bank cross infection (now more often in the modus that new or old bad fiscal decisions and doubts about sovereign debts are infecting their banks in e.g. the UK, Italy and in Greece) would be e.g. nationalisation or a state aid loan at non-market rates or conditions. Even though such measures are often financially beneficial to the investing state in the long term, the potential for high-risk and especially the sheer amount of money needed for the initial public investment has influenced the introduction of barriers to public sector intervention. More specifically, any use of public funds now needs to be preceded by the bail-in of shareholders, junior bondholders and then senior creditors, such as current account holders above 100.000 euro. Creatively, Italy has introduced its Atlante/Atlas fund as a private sector alternative to state aid, but there are continuing doubts whether the Italian financial sector, based in an over-indebted country, is sturdy enough as a whole for the least weak institutions to help out their weakest colleagues.
Even though at least three of the legs of a banking union (EBA in the whole of the EU, and SRM and SSM in the Eurozone) are now in their operational phase, the responsibility for coming up with the funding for solutions appears to continue to be territorial. The SRM is still building up its funding, and it is no doubt difficult to determine when it should grasp the reins from the SSM and take control and responsibility for a concrete solution. In the mean time, local funds and savings account holders tend to be the biggest category of bail-inable creditors, once the more sophisticated financial sector investors have decided not to invest in shares or coco’s of a troubled bank, or are dumping such shares or bail-inable bonds at the first hint of trouble. In the case of amongst others Italy, this is a political issue as a recent bail-in showed that many of the bail-inable creditors are consumers and small and medium sized enterprises. Agreeing that the Single Resolution Board of the SRM takes charge, means accepting that these voters will suffer. These are the same taxpayers who were supposed to benefit from the fact that ‘taxpayer money’ should only be in play after bail-in had taken place (but instead suffer most). The least sophisticated players are the most likely investors in the bail-inable unsecured bank bonds that at the moment do not pay a credible risk premium in the central bank stimulated low interest environment. A territorial approach does not work in a rich but stretched country such as Italy, however, nor is the health of Italian banks of interest only to other Italian banks, the health of Deutsche or the smaller community banks only of interest to Germany, or the health of the UK financial system upon Brexit only of interest to other UK banks. The reputation and financial health of all banks in the Eurozone, in the EU, and perhaps even in the world are now soundly linked in our open financial system, with information, distrust and fear propagating quickly on the internet. This should make it in the joint interest of the member states and governments of other financial centres to stand together, but the aforementioned public opinion and a sovereign tradition of not helping each other across borders when there are solvency issues at banking groups of which the top holding is licensed elsewhere, are preventing this.
Nothing is, however, preventing banks and other key bits of the international financial infrastructure such as CCP’s to step up themselves. Regardless of whether Atlante/Atlas was voluntary or set up under political pressure, it would appear in the calculated self-interest of such institutions to create – as they did some decades or in some cases such as the UK centuries ago – a new central bank from their midst, to deal with this issue that no bank or member state can deal with unilaterally. Strong appearing financial groups can become weak almost overnight if the banking system is distrusted or an incident in one of their subsidiaries occurs (AIG, Citi, Deutsche, Unicredit, RBS, Fortis are examples that come to mind), so it would be in wise for both currently high ranking and for currently low ranking banks to participate in a new private sector bail-out structure that would be able, allowed and willing to act. And no doubt such a EU or worldwide private sector bail-out fund could count on a high rating, and a low tax environment, especially if it is set up as a charity instead of as a profit centre (perhaps with any profits allocated to help out bail-in victims, or to sponsor financial education of consumers and small enterprises). Taking action themselves, jointly, in the common interest but by voluntarily putting up their own money would not least also give a valid emotional argument for allowing them to set their own course again, instead of being regulated to the max as is the current regulatory trajectory for the still nominally ‘private’ sector activity of banking, and thus take control of their own destiny again by also picking up the tab if things go wrong.
This is because depression will not tadalafil india online unica-web.com only affect you mentally but also physically as well. tadalafil in canada Make sure that a stimulant of romantic and sexual nature exists. These days’ problems like sexual dysfunction, premature ejaculation, erectile dysfunction, penis shrinkage and low sex unica-web.com sildenafil tablets uk desire. Benefits levitra vs cialis of these coupons are you get the medication that differs from generic drug only by its known name. So my question would be to the banks: where is the new private sector central bank?




Bank bail-in consequences for pension funds, insurers and the consumers dependent on them

A new component of the recovery and resolution framework for banks is the mandatory bail-in of shareholders and unsecured creditors that will become mandatory across the EU at the latest in 2016. The bail-in of creditors has been introduced to avoid having member states (ultimately at the expense of its taxpayers) chipping in to bail out a bank that is too important for its economy to let fail. As a policy choice this is understandable, even if much of the initial investment in bailing out a failing bank is normally recouped when the bank or its assets are sold at a later point in time (unless the public sector owner manages the bank for other public policy reasons than recouping its investment).

For subsets of depositors/investors at banks the new mandatory bail-in at the behest of resolution authorities requires a new mind-set in risk management. Specifically this applies to those depositors holding funds at the bank that are not protected under the applicable depositor guarantee system, such as companies or individuals keeping more than 100.000 euro at the bank, or (from 2019) those that bought bonds issued by the bank.

The new rules aim to the public budget, while continuing to protect small depositors, and anyone with a secured claim on the bank (such as central banks). Really new in this line-up is the protection of the public budget, or as politicians/legislators name it: ‘the taxpayer’. Increasing the protection for the public budget does mean that the losses will have to be suffered by someone else, in this case the ‘senior unsecured creditors’ that used to rely on (1) implicit government support for large banks, (2) good banking supervision that would fail and liquidate the bank when it was still solvent enough to pay back each senior unsecured creditor after the liquidation process, or (3) for bondholders that qualify as consumers or small companies on the explicit deposit guarantee system for bond portfolios up to 100.000 euro. These are all in the process of being removed, as senior unsecured creditors will no longer be protected under any of them but instead will be forcibly bailed in when there are signs that the bank might be in trouble. The thinking is probably that very wealthy individuals will ultimately bear these costs, but in practice the impact is more likely to be suffered by pension funds, insurers, banks, investment funds that hold cash at the bank in their current accounts, have bonds or own shares issued by the bank, or have to replenish deposit guarantee systems that have to cough up the cash under a bail-in. And by the consumers and companies dependent on them of course.

Though the commitments to the pension fund of the employees of the failing bank are protected, any debts to other pension funds or insurance companies are fair game. Regulators can still opt – in an optional and thus non-dependable manner – to exclude bail-inable creditors at the moment of the bail-in if they for instance fear unrest. This might benefit certain senior creditors, but will only increase the burden on the remaining senior creditors that do not get this benefit from the resolution authorities (for instance because they are based in another member state, or are too small to start a crisis if they in turn fail due to writing down the money they had entrusted to the bank).

For bonds, the exclusion from deposit guarantee protection and accompanying bail-in-ability may be somewhat defendable (in spite of the potential financial instability risks of writing down bank bond values), as long as the right risk premium is paid by the bank for this risk. I understand that after downgrades of bank bonds by rating agencies in anticipation of the bail-in instrument, the (ultra low) interest rates on unsecured senior debt have shown an increase in the risk premium paid to investors in such bonds. It is doubtful whether that risk premium is enough to compensate for the de facto highly increased risk that bank supervisors will deem a bank to be potentially in trouble and potentially to cause financial instability, and ‘rescuing’ the bank by increasing its capital by writing down or converting these bonds. This can and perhaps should be judged part of normal risk management at the institutions investing in such bonds. It could be a conscious assessment by a well-trained lender that the likelihood of such an event is sufficiently low per bank in a diversified portfolio of bank bonds that even at the current low interest rates the small add-on constitutes an acceptable risk premium. Perhaps. For non-deposit protected consumers and non-financial companies that invest spare cash in bank bonds after the deposit insurance expires for bank bonds in 2019 it is unlikely to be as well prepared for.

A risk perhaps less well understood is that any cash held at any bank on a savings/payment/current account (to the extent it exceeds the coverage by the deposit guarantee system or collateral, and thus also constitutes a so-called senior unsecured credit) is subject to the same write down or conversion as unsecured bonds are. For instance, if a pension funds uses one single bank to collect the liquidity needed to make out the monthly payments to its pensioners, it is in fact making a high risk investment in the bank. This high risk materialises if the banks’ supervisor and resolution authority decide that the time for failing the bank has come before the order for the transfer to pensioners has been given. The bank will in that case re-open the next Monday as usual, but the cash needed by the pension fund to make the payment to pensioners will no longer be available as such cash was bailed-in. The supervisor/resolution authority may or may not give an exemption to the bail-in, but this would increase the burden for others (and is certainly not a right of the pension fund).

The main dependable exception is if the bank gives collateral to the owner of the cash, in the example to the pension fund. Senior unsecured debt is bail-inable, but secured debt is excluded. This is for instance the case with central bank loans that will be collateralized by sovereign bonds or other acceptable collateral. Other examples are for funds owed in the clearing and settlement process, or in the case of bonds so-called pfandbriefe and other covered bonds (that are secured by specific assets of the bank). Small pension funds and small insurers will normally not have the market power or political power to ensure such security is given to them for payment accounts. If they do not get it, they may be wise to spread their cash holdings over a wide range of banks in order to avoid potentially losing all their cash in one go. They could also seek insurance e.g. via derivatives on the potential that a bank will fail, but that may be costly, and it would need to be certain that the writer of that derivative/insurance is not itself linked to or exposed to the bank that is failing.

Should the shares in a bank, bonds issued by a bank, and savings held at a bank by an institutional investor be bailed in, this may have an impact on its own obligations to pay out. An investment fund will be worth less (and so will the pro rata investments by its investors, and the investors in such investors), which may or may not have been understood by those investing via such a fund. At an insurance company or pension fund it may mean that premiums will need to be increased, or payouts reduced. Though their clients may not always be taxpayers in the country where the bank was based, they will definitely be taxpayers somewhere. Taxpayers will thus still bear the costs directly or indirectly via their pension funds, investment funds and insurance firms. The main change is that this burden will only to a lesser extent arrive via state budgets (which will still contract due to lower tax receipt as a result of the losses suffered by banks, insurers, and individual taxpayers, as well as via bailed-in cash held by municipalities, provinces and other state bodies at the bank). The main advantage is the public relations benefit that the burden will not go via the state budget immediately, and that the costs – if pension funds, insurers etcetera have limited their risks via risk management – will be spread out over time and many consumers. Small increases in premiums or limits to payments are less noticeable than a big headline number of initial investment by the state in a traditional bailout. Saving the taxpayer by bailing taxpayers in (directly or indirectly) does, however, appear to be logically impossible.

Being mentally healthy viagra pfizer canada is very important for us. These herbal supplements have achieved the recognition of being the most popular aphrodisiac herb, it can provide relief to a number generico cialis on line great website of sexual health issues. This means that since they are not only beneficial for sexual health but also are a key to commander levitra Get More Information overall rejuvenation and vitality. Ball and Socket Joints- Permit for Click Here buy cialis wide range of rotation and movement. Also see:

– Recital 1, 5, 8, 31, 67 and art 44, 47, 48, 108, 109 and 130 BRRD directive 2014/59/EU

– Recital 5 and 6 Recast Banking Directive 2006/48/EC (part of the previous version of the CRD)

– Art 27 SRB regulation 806/2014

– Art 1.1 and 1.4 of the currently applicable Deposit guarantee directive 1994/19/EC, and Recital 47 and art 5, 20 and 21 Deposit guarantee directive 2014/49/EU (of which 5.1 sub k on excluding bonds will be applicable from July 2019)

– Italy/Romanelli, EU Court of Justice 11 February 1999, Case C-366/97, §13-15.

EU Banking Supervision, chapter 4.4, 18 and 19

Are EU Banks Safe?, chapter 3




Variable mortgage risk weighting – Procyclical or anticyclical timing?

Increasing mortgage loan risk weights in a depressed property market is likely to be procyclical, as would reducing risk weights in booming property market. Strangely, this procyclicality appears to be acceptable under the contemplated EBA standards on adjusting risk weights due to financial stability considerations that are currently out for consultation. The draft binding rules do not specify when they should best be adjusted up, and when down, nor how to take into account such potential procyclical effects. Nothing in the proposed binding rules clarifies at which part of the cycle this lever should be used, which is a bit odd for nominally technical rules that have as their key ingredient that a specific lever can be used for financial stability considerations.

The EBA proposals do give a clue as to what information is relevant, but mainly leave the type of response to the supervisor itself. A supervisor eager to apply the law in a conservative manner is left scratching his head as to the optimum course and timing. A supervisor eager or under political or monetary policy pressure to boost a growing economy, or to stop a sliding property market, is free to do whatever it wants even if the longer term effects might be a less safe banking system. For example, the economies of many of the member states currently need a stimulus. Increasing house prices and office prices based on cheaper lending – if banks do not need to hold so much capital – could help provide such a stimulus. Even though bad lending practices and too low risk premiums and risk buffers for mortgage loans in the USA subprime sector actually kicked off the latest worldwide crisis, the solution to help growth in the short term could be to keep risk weights low, and to keep all options open for national legislators and supervisors. As a result of such pressures it is difficult to blame EBA and its voting members for building in this leeway. However, it does mean that the new binding rules are not very useful if a supervisor or financial stability regulator would like to be able to take measures to ensure the stability of the banking sector and/or the property market. The standards instead excel in less than clear guidance such as ‘Take into account housing market developments’, which kicks in a wide-open door, and says nothing on whether rising values or buyers interest should lead to an increase in risk weighting (and thus higher capital requirements), or to a decrease in risk weighting (and thus lower capital requirements).

This leaves aside that a discussion could be had on whether a higher risk weight would be best from a technical point of view in the upslope of a boom (to stop irrational exuberance, and build up capital buffers for the eventual decline in property values a few years hence and thus in an anticyclical manner), or on the downslope towards a trough (to increase the potential for bank capital being sufficient to deal with future losses in a value-declining property market, thus limiting the scope for banks to lend to potential new purchasers and forcing them to double down capital for existing and new downward developing mortgage loans, even though for the wider economy this would be procyclical). In this light, an analysis performed by supervisors on the basis of the lengthy data sets available over the boom period and the bust in immovable property markets in almost every member state could have been used to base these standards on an analysis of the costs and benefits of heightening and reducing risk weights in each national or regional property market in the period from e.g. 2000 until now. Indicating when Dutch, Spanish, Irish or any other national supervisor in hindsight would have wished that they used the existing risk weight-adjustment instrument either in a pro- or anticyclical manner during that period might lead to useful indicators as to when it should be used in the future with the best impact on wider financial stability as well as on the resilience provided by larger bank financial buffers.

A compromise solution could be to try to aim for the upper slopes of the boom for an increase, and reduce it when property prices have gone below reasonable long term values. At the bottom of the trough this would stimulate the housing market, especially if the expected losses on the housing portfolio have already been written down in full under a possibly wider definition of default and/or lower valuation of the collateral. Higher risk weights on the remaining fully covered mortgage loans would then no longer be necessary, if – and only if – the risk weight setter is able to correctly call when a boom is under way, or when a property market recession is entering irrationally depressed territory.

It would thus be helpful if the standards clarify whether their primary target is to stabilise the immovable property market in a certain market segment, or to stabilise the banks that lend in that area even if that means restricting loans to a already plummeting property market, or both. That would also help indicate whether there is a need to coordinate across financial sectors and across banks on the standardised and IRB approach (to ensure that banks, insurers, pension funds and other non-bank mortgage loan providers increase or decrease their exposure to the market segment involved in the same manner) which I would favour, or not (to ensure that the banks are safe by being able – to put it bluntly – to offload the risky and more costly exposure to the overheated property segment, even if that is to unsuspecting insurers or securitisation-investors such as pension funds).

This overall lack of clear indicators and purposes means that I am a bit reluctant to criticise the only clear benchmark that EBA does provide, which has been referenced in the draft standards and made more concrete in the impact assessment. According to it, loss expectations should be a key factor to determine how high the risk weights should be. It is a welcome clarification of intent, and something supervisors might be benchmarked to. However, though I applaud its inclusion, this specific benchmark does clarify two things that in view of pro and anti-cyclical thinking are a bit unwelcome. The first is that higher loss expectations are expected to be the trigger for an increase in risk weighting. As soon as market based loss expectations are made the determining factor, any irrationality in the market suddenly becomes less easy to deal with. This irrationality is part of the accepted market wisdom at that time, so if for ten years prices have gone up, no one ‘expects’ losses any more. Only once the bust period actually arrives, loss expectations suddenly swing up (sometimes to irrational heights in a panic). Increasing risk weights at that point in time will only strengthen the slide into the abyss. If risk weights instead are already up when loss expectations are still close to nil, then the lever could helpfully be used to lighten the load on the way down, helping to dampen the cycle. That does, however, require supervisors actually to take a stand against ‘the sky is the limit’ politicians and realtors, which as indicated above may not be their favoured role.

Second, the table appears to indicate that the lowest risk weights are appropriate in ‘normal’ times. If so, the lever of risk weights is unavailable during the entire trough of the cycle, meaning it has no dampening effect to get the market (and the banks’ capital requirements) into a mood that indicates light at the end of the tunnel. From a macroprudential point of view, that seems unhelpful. The lowest risk weights should be only in force at the ‘apex’ of the bust, so that the lever can be used both in the downswing and the upswing. No doubt this is more the role of the ESRB to point out, but strangely their role as providers of warnings and advisors on the cyclicality of draft-rules is not visibly reflected in the EBA draft standards.

In conclusion, it may be good to re-assess and clarify some of the key concepts, main goals and direction of adjustments in the draft binding rules before they enter into force. Building upon the experience in the past crisis with a ‘in hindsight’ analysis as to when and how this tool would have been most effective and efficient would be helpful. Both changes would help shelter banking supervisors from being put under pressure to sacrifice long term bank stability against short term political pressure for economic growth.

Also see:

  • The separate comment on adjusting the mortgage risk weights
  • EU Banking Supervision, chapter 6.2, 6.5, 8, 18.3, 21.2-21.4, and 22.5
  • 124-126 CRR
  • 128.2 sub d CRR
  • 164-166 CRR
  • EBA consultation paper EBA/CP/2015/12 of 6 July 2015 on determining higher risk-weights

This drug needs to be utilized only on line levitra once every day. Vacuum Devices: Such devices levitra side effects are help to improve semen load. By all means, he online pharmacy for levitra prides himself in keeping her happy. Although women use about 15 buying viagra without prescription percent of the testosterone be it administered or natural, remains in a state that is bound which makes it very useless for muscle building.




Mortgage loan risk weights go up (and down?)

Banks that provide mortgage loans can be subject to more or less risk depending on for instance developments in house prices and house shortages in countries or cities. This means they need to hold more financial buffers or less financial buffers depending on the risk that the loan will not be repaid in full, which shift in prudential buffer demands in turn affects housing affordability for most buyers (and thus stimulates or dampens the housing market). EBA is now consulting on the ‘regulatory standards’ on varying the risk weighting for mortgage loans for both homes (residential property) and commercial properties such as shops and offices due to such financial stability considerations. The consultation paper is fostering this discussion very helpfully, but still has some severe shortcomings if it were to become law in this way, one of them is that it only deals with the increase of the risk weight, not with the decrease thereof, the effect of this information on the market, nor the changes in prices and risk over time. Another concern is the lack of clear rules on the timing these supervisory interventions in the financial cycle, which is the subject of a separate comment.

The headline risk rate for immovable property backed loans in the standardised approach to credit risk is that they should be risk weighted at 100%. This headline risk rate is, however, only used if some rather lenient criteria set by the CRR are not fulfilled. If sufficiently backed by qualifying homes, shops or offices the risk weight is sharply reduced (to 35 or 50 %). For the internal model based approach, there is an equivalent possibility to reduce or increase the LGD factor. The result is that banks normally only have to hold a reduced amount of financial buffers on residential and commercial types of mortgage loans. The only exception is if these criteria on the relative value of the collateral to the loan are found not to be fulfilled, and – and this is the subject of the consultation – when supervisors indicate that the reduction in perceived risk is not opportune at that moment in time, or even demand an additional slice of capital by increasing the risk weighting for commercial and residential mortgage loans to up to 150%.

Lets leave aside that the definitions of the terms used are as clear as tar (of the type of definition that residential property means a property that is a residence) and thus highly likely to be moulded not only to local practices but also to the lowest risk requirements. Lets also leave aside that if the supervisors set a high risk weight of 150%, it might be miraculously decided by the bank that the collateral is no longer sufficient, in which case the back-up risk weight of 100% will start to apply in accordance with the badly worded CRR provisions. Lets focus instead on the good intention that sometimes it would be good to require more capital, and sometimes less, for the good of the immovable property market and of the individual mortgage providers active in it.

The 150% risk weight is actually not new. It existed also in previous versions of the capital requirements directives, but was one of those territories that sounded good in theory but in practice were not used. In the depths of the subprime crisis, these levers gained new attention, and even a modicum of followers. For the standardised approach, some member states have now introduced stricter requirements on the lowest risk weighting, and some member states increased the risk weighting to 100% (none yet to the maximum of 150%). For the internal model based approach, only Norway (which is outside of the EU but covered by the CRR provisions under the EEA treaty) has used the possibility to increase the LGD factor in the internal model approach to credit risk (though other supervisors, however, may have done this too in an ad hoc manner as part of the model approval process). This is one of the macro/micro prudential levers that directly impact on the banks’ capital requirements for mortgage loans, and thus on the property market in specified regions (either in a whole country like Greece, or just in overheating segments such as London or Amsterdam). The weird thing is that the proposed regulation only addresses the ‘when should the requirement go up’ question, and ignores the equally important ‘when and how should the requirement go down’.

Even though this tool formally addresses only the capital position of individual banks, it applies to each domestic and foreign bank that is active in a specific property market, and thus will impact – intentionally it appears – on market prices in that area, by increasing or decreasing mortgage availability and interest rate levels. Hopefully, a similar restriction will apply to non-bank mortgage providers, though how this is ensured for specialised institutions or e.g. insurers is equally not addressed in the CRR or consultation paper. If the risk weight change might even potentially be a market-moving event, it is as important to give clarity on when the risk weight percentage or LGD should go down as on when it should go up. If this is not immediately clear from the new contemplated laws, the supervisor will join monetary authorities in their catch 22 of never being able to increase the interest rates if the only thing holding up market prices and holding back a recession is the fact that the market does not expect such an increase in interest rates. That the monetary interest rate dilemma relates also to bond and other financial instrument prices instead of – like this specific instance of mortgage loan risk weighting – only impacts on house prices and affordability does not really matter. If the risk weight is stuck at either a high or low value due to unclear criteria and potential market moving impact, it becomes useless as a macro economic and micro prudential lever.

In addition, the proposed rules should be clear on how supervisors should determine when the risk requirement goes up, but also how they clarify to the market when it certainly will go down again, and how gradual that decline will be. As market prices in the defined segment will be impacted – at least if they are intended to be useful – both by the decision to go up and by the decision to climb down (by reducing or increasing the exposure of the banks to that segment, and making new mortgage loans more expensive or cheaper) in a parallel to the insider information rules the obligatory decision-path and the communication plan of the supervisor involved should be very clear indeed. The consultation paper is silent on the communication plan that should have accompanied it, which is a serious defect on any issue that will and should impact overheating or collapsing housing markets.

To be fair, EBA’s drafting problems derive in part from unclear or one sided drafting of the CRR itself, which focuses solely on the going up variety, and ignores cross-sector and insider-information type concerns. Perhaps the attention of prudential supervisors and housing market organisations could have been better asked for and used at the time of drafting of the related CRR provision, which now contains pitfalls (what is the impact on the bank’s profitability, on their market share compared to other providers, why is there only a level playing field between banks on a specific approach, and not between banks on different approaches, and would a gradual build up and decrease not be better than the sharp cliffs now envisaged, and why do the increases not impact immediately on new mortgage loans, alongside a gradual build up for the existing mortgage loan portfolio?). And what should be the impact on the interest rates agreed in the existing loan portfolio, and is this a public policy concern (which it might well be if it impacts on the financial health of house owners), or is it an issue that can be left to banks (by introducing an additional component into their contractual interest rate calculation and adaptation).

In short, even within the boundaries of the sketchy provisions in the CRR, the consultation paper could be helpfully improved by filling in some of the blanks on adjusting these risk weight provisions both down and up, and on cross-sector cooperation as well as good communication. In an area as important as housing markets, leaving this to national discretion or to market participants may not be the best course. In addition, the related CRR provisions might be adjusted to improve their effectiveness.

 

Also see:

  • The separate comment on timing these supervisory interventions
  • Art. 124-126 CRR
  • Art. 128.2 sub d CRR
  • Art. 164-166 CRR
  • EBA consultation paper EBA/CP/2015/12 of 6 July 2015 on determining higher risk-weights,
  • EBA overview of notifications on 124 and on 164 CRR
  • EBA Q&A 2014-1214
  • EU Banking Supervision, chapter 6.2, 8, and 16.6.

Finally, if you want to get your license. discounts on viagra you could try these out purchase levitra online Commonly, doxycycline is an antibiotic of the fluoroquinolone class. So is it possible to purchase brand cialis price without prescription? No. levitra is an RX medication that requires doctor’s prescription to purchase. The generic cialis india should be taken to have good information on the storage pattern of the pill.