1

Where are the new private sector central banks?

For the past 8 years banks have had it rough. Partly they had themselves to blame, partly this is the result of lax (or light touch, or ‘growth oriented’ stimulative) government legislation and action. Anti-banking public opinion and the subsequent more stringent state aid rules and bail in requirements are currently preventing public sector measures that are needed to create short-term financial stability. Now in the news are Monte dei Paschi di Siena and Deutsche Bank, but similar stories have been available in the past across the EU, and at certain times in e.g. the USA and China. For troubled banks there do not appear to be voluntary private sector interventions, and forcefully ‘inviting’ stronger banks to buy their weaker brethren does not work because either the stronger banks are too strong relative to their supervisor, or too weak to bear the cross alone, or are themselves part of the weaker side of the system. Normally the state balance sheet would now be used to prop up the relevant bits of the financial infrastructure. Examples of such traditional public sector solutions for banks overwhelmed by non performing loans, sovereign/bank cross infection (now more often in the modus that new or old bad fiscal decisions and doubts about sovereign debts are infecting their banks in e.g. the UK, Italy and in Greece) would be e.g. nationalisation or a state aid loan at non-market rates or conditions. Even though such measures are often financially beneficial to the investing state in the long term, the potential for high-risk and especially the sheer amount of money needed for the initial public investment has influenced the introduction of barriers to public sector intervention. More specifically, any use of public funds now needs to be preceded by the bail-in of shareholders, junior bondholders and then senior creditors, such as current account holders above 100.000 euro. Creatively, Italy has introduced its Atlante/Atlas fund as a private sector alternative to state aid, but there are continuing doubts whether the Italian financial sector, based in an over-indebted country, is sturdy enough as a whole for the least weak institutions to help out their weakest colleagues.
Even though at least three of the legs of a banking union (EBA in the whole of the EU, and SRM and SSM in the Eurozone) are now in their operational phase, the responsibility for coming up with the funding for solutions appears to continue to be territorial. The SRM is still building up its funding, and it is no doubt difficult to determine when it should grasp the reins from the SSM and take control and responsibility for a concrete solution. In the mean time, local funds and savings account holders tend to be the biggest category of bail-inable creditors, once the more sophisticated financial sector investors have decided not to invest in shares or coco’s of a troubled bank, or are dumping such shares or bail-inable bonds at the first hint of trouble. In the case of amongst others Italy, this is a political issue as a recent bail-in showed that many of the bail-inable creditors are consumers and small and medium sized enterprises. Agreeing that the Single Resolution Board of the SRM takes charge, means accepting that these voters will suffer. These are the same taxpayers who were supposed to benefit from the fact that ‘taxpayer money’ should only be in play after bail-in had taken place (but instead suffer most). The least sophisticated players are the most likely investors in the bail-inable unsecured bank bonds that at the moment do not pay a credible risk premium in the central bank stimulated low interest environment. A territorial approach does not work in a rich but stretched country such as Italy, however, nor is the health of Italian banks of interest only to other Italian banks, the health of Deutsche or the smaller community banks only of interest to Germany, or the health of the UK financial system upon Brexit only of interest to other UK banks. The reputation and financial health of all banks in the Eurozone, in the EU, and perhaps even in the world are now soundly linked in our open financial system, with information, distrust and fear propagating quickly on the internet. This should make it in the joint interest of the member states and governments of other financial centres to stand together, but the aforementioned public opinion and a sovereign tradition of not helping each other across borders when there are solvency issues at banking groups of which the top holding is licensed elsewhere, are preventing this.
Nothing is, however, preventing banks and other key bits of the international financial infrastructure such as CCP’s to step up themselves. Regardless of whether Atlante/Atlas was voluntary or set up under political pressure, it would appear in the calculated self-interest of such institutions to create – as they did some decades or in some cases such as the UK centuries ago – a new central bank from their midst, to deal with this issue that no bank or member state can deal with unilaterally. Strong appearing financial groups can become weak almost overnight if the banking system is distrusted or an incident in one of their subsidiaries occurs (AIG, Citi, Deutsche, Unicredit, RBS, Fortis are examples that come to mind), so it would be in wise for both currently high ranking and for currently low ranking banks to participate in a new private sector bail-out structure that would be able, allowed and willing to act. And no doubt such a EU or worldwide private sector bail-out fund could count on a high rating, and a low tax environment, especially if it is set up as a charity instead of as a profit centre (perhaps with any profits allocated to help out bail-in victims, or to sponsor financial education of consumers and small enterprises). Taking action themselves, jointly, in the common interest but by voluntarily putting up their own money would not least also give a valid emotional argument for allowing them to set their own course again, instead of being regulated to the max as is the current regulatory trajectory for the still nominally ‘private’ sector activity of banking, and thus take control of their own destiny again by also picking up the tab if things go wrong.
This is because depression will not tadalafil india online unica-web.com only affect you mentally but also physically as well. tadalafil in canada Make sure that a stimulant of romantic and sexual nature exists. These days’ problems like sexual dysfunction, premature ejaculation, erectile dysfunction, penis shrinkage and low sex unica-web.com sildenafil tablets uk desire. Benefits levitra vs cialis of these coupons are you get the medication that differs from generic drug only by its known name. So my question would be to the banks: where is the new private sector central bank?




Renegotiate the EEA post Brexit

A new post-Brexit trade arrangement between the UK and the EU will be complex to negotiate, and likely to be made more complex by rejection trauma. From the point of view of long term economic growth, stable financial markets and cross border peaceful cooperation, there does not appear to be good news. Position papers like the Japanese give strong hints on what is needed, but also emphasize that the UK needs automatic access to the single market more than the EU needs access to UK markets. Even if the overall size of the European economy might shrink if London suffers, the transfer of even only some crumbs of its current business would mean additional local jobs in Amsterdam, Frankfurt or Paris, trumping any benefits of keeping the London financial markets alive.
So, how to turn it around, and make the shortsighted Brexit vote (costing UK voters jobs, subsidies and workers protection) and a lack of decisive political action from UK and EU legislators to avoid this course of action, into something that would benefit Europe as a whole?
One route that has not yet received sufficient attention is a renegotiated EEA (European Economic Area, consisting of the EU member states plus three non-EU member states). So far, the ‘Norway-option’ or EEA has only been mentioned as a halfway house, where the UK could seek temporary refuge under the current provisions of the EEA Treaty (if the EEA member states would be willing to allow this). Such refuge would allow continued access to the EU single market, as well as possibly to a range of existing trade agreements with third countries. However, like for the current non-EU EEA countries, there is a rather high price to pay for single market access via this route. The current EEA Treaty of 1993 (between the EU member states plus Norway, Liechtenstein and Iceland) allows access to the EU for the three in exchange for abiding fully by EU single market legislation and paying into the EU budget, on both of which they have no say at all. In essence they are being taxed without being represented (in exchange for single market access). For instance new banking requirements have to be accepted by the three countries in exactly the way they are agreed by the EU member states. This was kind of ok at the time, when for instance EU banking legislation was still relatively low key and required implementation by local legislators into local law, but more intrusive EU regulations and directives have de facto increased the transfer of Norwegian, Icelandic and Liechtenstein’ sovereignty to the EU. The Swiss were key drivers behind the negotiations for the 1993 EEA Treaty, but before it entered into force they opted out in a referendum. Swiss banks and stock exchanges, and other businesses for which there are no specific arrangements to access the EU suffer as a result. Norway, Liechtenstein and Iceland have gained access for their banks, but they suffer from having no vote in the council, no vote in parliament and no vote at EBA and ESMA.
The economic and political interests of the UK on the one hand and Switzerland, Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein may thus well be aligned for a new treaty that keeps the EEA benefits, but adds a bit of balance to the sovereignty transfer. That is, if the UK can indeed convince Norway, Liechtenstein and Iceland that it can act decisively, and in their common interest instead of only its own (of which Iceland may need some convincing). They might do so, if a revamped EEA deal could bring back some of their sovereignty on single market issues, and there is not only a fair voting arrangement with the EU member states, but also amongst the non-EU member states of the revamped EEA. Arrangements on voting on new legislation could for example be based on the Eurozone ins and outs voting arrangements at EBA, though it would thus need to be drafted to ensure that the ‘outs’ are not dominated by any single non-EU EEA member state. Adding the economic and financial services heft of the UK and Switzerland onto the existing access to the single market of the non-EU EEA states, might sway the EU member states to add such a provision to the EEA Treaty.
One of the first things people note when they start viagra fast delivery like it adding Acai to their diet so as to get all the essential nutrients from it. Movie locations in California vary from cialis soft 20mg urban city setting to beautiful scenery of hills and beaches, all of which help in fighting cancer.No cycling: Traditional bike seats are leaf shaped with a nose at the front. As an added bonus, products like this tend to improve the over all well being of person. buying tadalafil tablets He said he didn’t know it well, which http://cute-n-tiny.com/cute-animals/cats-in-halloween-costumes/ purchase viagra no prescription I found hard to believe because I had seen him kick a wall harder than a donkey kicks a pervert. For the UK becoming part of a wider single market EEA renegotiation instead of being stuck in a bilateral post-Brexit negotiation would solve several EU/UK problems in one go. Gifts such as continued single market access, a say in financial services legislation and a more ‘sovereign’ vote on single market initiatives can more easily be granted to the joint non-EU EEA states than only to the UK. It would allow a path for the Swiss to opt in (solving their own internal referendum troubles on free movement of EU citizens), and perhaps even some of the other EU candidates that might be more acceptable to EU-voters as single market EEA candidates than as EU candidates. Last but not least it would allow the single market to remain intact and reduce negative fallout on joint external interests such as security and defence.
It would still require some hard choices on customs, taxes, security, the EFTA trade agreements and especially on passport free travel and migration. For instance the likely limitation cross border long term migration rights only to people in jobs or after retirement from a local job is a common electoral issue for both the Swiss and the British (following referenda in both countries). To gain or regain access to the single market with such a painful sacrifice for the EU member states, would require equally hurtful sacrifices of the Swiss and UK negotiators.
Which price for instance the UK wants to offer up first to Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein, and then to the EU member states would be up to it to consider. Any offer would need to be of the level of the level of sacrifice in internal UK politics as e.g. exchanging the pound for the euro. Schengen accession and doing its share on burden sharing in finance or refugees would be a good starting point, as it would ease existing troubles with e.g. France on the Calais encampment. A prudential regime for wholesale markets, desirable from a macro-prudential point of view, could be another offer, building on the AIFMD regime for wholesale investment funds. Regardless of the exact result of mutually beneficial EEA renegotiations, this route would provide the UK with the opportunity to show again why it used to be the most influential and effective EU member state alongside France and Italy, before this influence was sacrificed on the altar of national short term electoral considerations. Changing the subject from post Brexit trade agreements to renegotiating the EEA would also provide EU negotiators with cover for granting favours to the UK, allow Switzerland a better entrance to the single market, and right an existing wrong in the EU/EEA of taxation without representation for Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein.